4.12.20
What drives social returns to education?
Schooling typically delivers significant private returns, with better educated individuals generally receiving higher earnings. However, the schooling of one person has also the potential to generate significant positive effects on other individuals, through formal and informal social interactions between them. Economists refer to these spillovers as ‘externalities’. These third-party effects also explain the wedge between private and social returns to education: while the former are typically estimated at 5% to 10%, the latter can be as high as 10% to 20%.
This non-technical blog summarises the findings of our recent GLO working paper, in which we seek to understand the factors behind different social returns to education, including the role of economic development. To do so, we conduct what we believe I the first meta-analysis of the social returns to education literature. We analyse over 1,000 econometric estimates from 31 articles published between 1993 and 2020. These articles cover 15 countries in total, a third of which are emerging or developing economies.
Some of our main findings are as follows:
First, education spillovers are stronger when measured at the workplace
(compared to the region, the industry or the country). This may be because people engage much more
directly and intensively within firms, including through face-to-face
communication. This
facilitates deeper interactions, through which the human capital obtained by
each worker from their schooling can more easily spillover to other individuals,
their colleagues, thus magnifying the social effect of schooling.
Second, tertiary schooling and schooling dispersion increase spillovers. It is widely believed that spillovers are
largely generated by highly-educated individuals, thus increase in tertiary
education appears to be a particularly relevant source of such externalities.
Moreover, spillovers tend to decrease as schooling dispersion in the labour
market shrinks.
In the limit, if every worker has the same level of schooling, a higher level
of schooling for the entire workforce may not lead to spillovers as there would
be no scope to learn from more-educated colleagues.
Third, spillovers slow down with economic development. This finding may be driven by the positive association between income and schooling levels at the cross-country level and the diminishing scope for spillovers as schooling levels increase. If a large share of the workforce already has higher levels of schooling, the scope for less-educated workers to learn from their more-educated co-workers is weaker, leading to lower spillovers.
In
conclusion, our findings support the continuing (public and private) investment
in schooling - including tertiary education – as they highlight the strong social
role of education. Education may promote world development both from an
individual private perspective but also in terms of the higher social returns
that it generates, in particular in emerging economies.
(Joint blog with Ying Cui)
<< Home